Month: November 2009

  • A Holiday Gift Idea for the Friend Who Has (Almost) Everything

    You may want to read some of the Customer Reviews before making your purchasing decision….
     

  • A new approach to economic equity

    Here’s a very prescient analysis and a fascinating suggestion for change that seems to have some traction in Ecuador and the U.K.  Could it ever work in the U.S.?  One Illinois representative thinks so.

    **********

    Have the Rich Won?

    Maybe not. A new approach to capping income at the top is starting to gain momentum.

    By Sam Pizzigati

    This article is from the November/December 2009 issue of Dollars & Sense: Real World Economics available at http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/2009/1109pizzigati.html

    issue 284 cover

    This article is from the November/December 2009 issue of Dollars & Sense magazine.

    Back in 1974, the inaugural year for Dollars & Sense, young
    economic justice activists—like me—felt we had our hands full. I was
    working, at the time, in upstate New York, helping mobile home owners
    organize against trailer park landlord extortion. I had one friend
    active on a campaign to win bargaining rights for the local
    university’s food service workers, another pushing for public housing,
    still another advocating for a badly needed primary health care clinic.

    Everywhere we all looked, we saw people hurting, we saw
    unfairness, we saw economic injustice. Now today, 35 years later, I’ve
    come to understand what we didn’t see: the big picture.

    Yes, back then in 1974, we certainly did face injustice at
    every turn. But we were living, thanks to years of struggle—and
    success—by our activist forebears, in a society where politics actually
    revolved around confronting those injustices and making change that
    could really help average working people.

    And, even better, we had a realistic shot at achieving that
    change. The reason? Our activist forbears had sliced the single
    greatest obstacle to social progress—the rich and powerful—down to
    democratic size. In 1974 we were living in a society with an enfeebled
    wealthy, and we didn’t know it.

    Shame on us. By not understanding—and not appreciating—the
    equality our progressive predecessors had battled so hard to achieve,
    we failed to defend it. We let the wealthy come back. We let grand
    concentrations of private wealth reconstitute themselves across the
    American economic landscape. We let the super rich regain their power
    to dictate and distort America’s political discourse.

    How rich—and powerful—have today’s rich become? Some numbers
    can help tell the story. In 1974, the most affluent 1% of Americans
    averaged, in today’s dollars, $380,000 in income.

    Now let’s fast-forward. In 2007, the most recent year with
    stats, households in America’s top 1% averaged $1.4 million, well over
    triple what top 1% households averaged back in 1974—and, remember, this
    tripling came after adjusting for inflation.

    Americans in the bottom 90%, meanwhile, saw their average
    incomes increase a meager $47 a year between 1974 and 2007, not enough
    to foot the bill for a month’s worth of cable TV.

    The bottom line: top-1% households made 12 times more income than bottom-90% households in 1974, 42 times more in 2007.

    The numbers become even more striking when we go back a bit
    further in time and focus not on the top 1%, but on the richest of the
    rich, the top 400, the living symbol of wealth and power in the United
    States ever since America’s original Gilded Age in the late 19th
    century.

    In 1955, our 400 highest incomes averaged $12.3 million, in
    today’s dollars. But the top 400 in 1955 didn’t get to enjoy all those
    millions. On average, after exploiting every tax loophole they could
    find, they actually paid over half their incomes, 51.2%, in federal
    income tax.

    Today’s super rich are doing better, fantastically better, both
    before and after taxes. In 2006, the top 400 averaged an astounding
    $263 million each in income. These 400 financially fortunate paid,
    after loopholes, just 17.2% of their incomes in federal tax.

    After taxes, as a group, the top 400 of 2006 had $84 billion
    more in their pockets than 1955’s top 400, $84 billion more they could
    put to work bankrolling politicians and right-wing think tanks and
    Swift Boat ad blitzes against progressive candidates and causes.

    How could America’s super rich have so little, relatively
    speaking, back in 1955 and so much today? What has changed between the
    mid 20th century and the first decade of the 21st? We have lost, simply
    put, the economic checks and balances that so significantly discouraged
    grand concentrations of private wealth in the years right after World
    War II.

    Among the most important of these checks and balances: steeply
    graduated progressive tax rates. Over most of the quarter-century
    between the early 1940s and the mid 1960s, America’s richest faced at
    least a 91% federal tax rate on “earned” income over $400,000. By 1974,
    that top rate had dropped, but only to a still steep 70%. The top rate
    today: 35%.

    Tax rates on income from the sale of stocks, bonds, and other
    property—capital gains—have traveled the same trend line. In the
    postwar years, the wealthy paid a 25% tax on capital gains. The current
    rate: just 15%.

    So what should today’s activists for economic justice do about
    all this? Hit the repeat button and re-fight the struggles of our
    activist forbears?

    That course certainly seems reasonable. Our forbears, after
    all, pulled off quite a stunner. They faced, a century ago, a super
    rich every bit as rich and powerful as the super rich we confront
    today. Over the course of the next half-century, they leveled that
    super rich.

    By the 1950s, the incomes of America’s richest had been
    “hacked to pieces,” as best-selling author Frederick Lewis Allen would
    marvel in a 1952 book. The grand estates of the super rich, jubilant
    postwar progressives would add, had become housing tracts and college
    campuses for the first mass middle class nation the world had ever
    seen.

    But this triumph would not stand the test of time. The 20th
    century would end as it began, with phenomenal wealth and power
    concentrated at America’s economic summit. By century’s end, the
    leveling institutions our progressive predecessors had fought so hard
    to win—progressive tax rates, a vital trade union presence, regulatory
    restrictions on corporate behavior—had all come unraveled.

    Maybe we ought to ask why, before we rush to re-fight the
    struggles our forbears so nobly waged. Why, for instance, did the
    single most potent leveling instrument of the mid 20th century, the
    steeply graduated rates of the progressive income tax, prove
    unsustainable?

    These steep rates, in their time, certainly did work wonders.
    In the mid 20th century, with these rates in effect, the U.S. economy
    essentially stopped generating colossal new concentrations of wealth
    and power. Of the 40 richest individuals in U.S. history, not one made
    the bulk of his fortune during the years of this progressive tax rate
    heyday.

    The big fortunes that did amass in these years mostly belonged
    to oil magnates. They enjoyed what the rest of America’s rich did not:
    a super loophole, the oil depletion allowance, that essentially
    shielded them from the stiff tax rates that applied to every other deep
    pocket.

    But steeply graduated tax rates have an Achilles heel. The rich
    hate them with an incredibly intense passion. That wouldn’t matter, of
    course, if everyone else loved these rates with equal fervor. But they
    don’t—because high tax rates on high incomes only impact the wealthy
    directly. The wealthy feel the “pain.” They also see no
    benefits—because they don’t need or use the public services high taxes
    on high incomes make possible.

    Those who do benefit from these public services, on the other
    hand, don’t automatically connect the availability of these services to
    progressive tax rates.

    The end result of these political dynamics: Steeply graduated
    tax rates—as traditionally structured—have never been able to stand the
    test of time, anywhere. The rich attack these rates with far more
    single-minded zeal than the general public supports them.

    High tax rates on high incomes typically only come into effect
    during periods of great social upheaval, during wars and severe
    economic downturns that knock the wealthy off their political stride.
    But after these upheavals, amid “normalcy,” the wealthy’s fervid and
    focused opposition to high rates eventually wears down the public
    political will to maintain these rates. The rates shrink, wealth
    re-concentrates.

    Today’s mainstream policy makers and politicos seem to have
    concluded, from this history, that any attempt to tax the rich
    significantly make no sense.

    The Obama White House, for instance, wants to up the top
    income tax rate on the wealthy, but just to the 39.6% rate in effect
    before the George W. Bush tax cuts. If the top U.S. tax rate does rise
    to 39.6%, America’s rich would be paying taxes at less than half the
    rate they faced in the 1950s under President Dwight D. Eisenhower, a
    Republican.

    Even worse: Merely repealing the Bush tax cuts, as current
    White House economist Lawrence Summers himself acknowledged in a 2007
    Brookings Institution paper, would only wipe away one-sixth of the
    income inequality the nation has experienced since 1979.

    Similar tax games are playing out in Britain, where the
    current government is upping the top tax rate on some high incomes from
    40 to 50%. The new rate would still constitute a bargain, by historical
    standards, for the British rich, who, at one point last century, faced
    a 97% top rate.

    Progressives in the UK, not surprisingly, are challenging their
    government’s tax-the-rich timidity. But they’re not stopping there.
    These progressives are also arguing that we need to go well beyond the
    traditional progressive tax remedies previous progressive generations
    put in place, beyond taxing the rich to actually capping their income.

    And this capping, these British progressives believe, ought to
    be done in a manner that gives average working families a clear and
    powerful vested self-interest in keeping the caps in place. How do they
    propose to accomplish this goal? They’re suggesting we link income
    ceilings at the top to income floors at the bottom. In effect, they
    seek a “maximum wage” tied to a minimum.

    With a “maximum” set as a multiple of a minimum, society’s
    richest and most powerful would only be able to increase their incomes
    if the incomes of society’s poorest and least powerful increased first.
    These rich, to become richer, have historically sought to depress
    wages. A maximum coupled to the minimum would instantly create a
    counter-incentive: the higher the wage at the bottom, the better for
    the rich—and the better, of course, for the bottom, too.

    In this new maximum wage environment, unions and other
    traditional advocates for higher wages at the bottom might suddenly
    find quite a few new—and distinctly wealthy—people in their corner.

    Leading UK progressives have opened a campaign to inject these
    notions into Britain’s mainstream political discourse. This past
    August, 100 British progressive luminaries—all-stars who included three
    dozen members of Parliament, veteran activists and economists, and the
    UK’s most important labor leader, Trades Union Congress general
    secretary Brendan Barber—called on their government to establish a
    “High Pay Commission” and “launch a wide-ranging review of pay at the
    top.”

    This High Pay Commission, the progressive luminaries urged,
    “should consider proposals to restrict excessive remuneration such as
    maximum wage ratios.”

    Thousands of British grassroots activists have since signed on
    to the High Pay Commission call. And one party in the British
    parliament, based in Wales, has already made advocacy for a UK-wide
    “maximum wage” part of its official platform.

    How exactly could a “maximum wage ratio” principle be
    implemented? Top-bottom ratios could be tied directly to the
    expenditure of tax dollars. A government could, for example, insist
    that all publicly owned enterprises limit the pay between their top
    executives and their workers.

    Late in 2007, delegates to Ecuador’s Constituent Assembly
    enacted legislation along this line. They created a remuneración
    máxima—a “maximum wage”—for all agencies and enterprises that take in
    over half their financing from tax dollars. The cap limits the pay of
    top executives in Ecuador’s publicly subsidized sector to 25 times the
    Ecuadorian minimum wage.

    Executives at Ecuador’s Banco del Pacifico, a huge bank
    nationalized after a 1999 financial crisis, have been able to exploit
    and expand exceptions in the original legislation. But the principle
    still stands.

    Governments could also apply that principle much more broadly,
    by mandating top-bottom pay ratios for any enterprises that seek
    government contracts or subsidies or tax breaks. The British
    government, as campaigners for a High Pay Commission note, could insist
    on “reasonable pay structures” within private enterprises that gain
    “public procurement contracts.”

    Under current law, in both Britain and the United States,
    private enterprises that win government contracts can pay their top
    executives as much as they please. The CEO at Lockheed Martin, a
    company that feeds almost exclusively off government contracts, last
    year took home $26.5 million. That’s over 700 times the take-home of
    the average American worker.

    Lockheed, of course, only represents the tip of the
    taxpayer-subsidized iceberg. Almost every major corporation and bank in
    the United States is currently raking in big-time taxpayer dollars,
    either through government contracts, economic development subsidies and
    tax breaks, or, most recently, outright billion-dollar bailouts.

    These taxpayer dollars are making rich people richer. Since
    the beginning of 2008, the Institute for Policy Studies recently
    reported, the 20 U.S. banks that have received the most bailout dollars
    have laid off 160,000 workers. The 100 top executives at these 20
    banks, in 2008 alone, collected a combined $791.5 million in personal
    compensation.

    Our tax dollars, in short, are increasing economic inequality
    in the United States. They are growing the gap between our richest and
    everyone else. That need not be. If we leveraged the power of the
    public purse—as we already do in the struggle against gender and racial
    inequality—our tax dollars could be helping us narrow, not expand, the
    economic gaps that divide us.

    Under existing U.S. law, companies that discriminate against
    women and minorities in their employment practices cannot gain
    government contracts. As a society, we’ve decided that we don’t want
    our tax dollars subsidizing companies that increase gender or racial
    inequality. So why should we let our tax dollars subsidize companies
    that increase economic inequality—by compensating top executives at
    levels that dwarf the pay that goes to average workers?

    Rep. Jan Schakowsky, a progressive Democrat from Illinois,
    doesn’t think we should. Schakowsky has introduced legislation, the
    Patriot Corporations Act, that would give tax breaks and a preference
    in the government contract bidding process to companies that pay their
    executives less than 100 times what they compensate their lowest-paid
    workers.

    That standard, suitably expanded and strengthened, could become
    a progressive principle worth rallying around: No tax dollars, in any
    way, shape, or form, for any companies or banks that pay their
    executives at over 25 times what their workers receive.

    Why 25 times? The President of the United States currently
    makes just under 25 times the annual pay of the lowest-paid federal
    worker. Why then should we let our tax dollars go to executives who
    demand—and get—hundreds of times more than their own workers?

    Back in 1974, in a far more equal United States, we never needed to ponder questions like these.
    Now we do.

    Sam Pizzigati is a labor journalist and an
    associate fellow at the Institute for Policy Studies, in Washington,
    D.C. He edits Too Much (www.toomuchonline.org), an online weekly on
    excess and inequality.

    Sources: For more on progressive tax rates in the United States, see the April 2009 Institute for Policy Studies report, Reversing the Great Tax Shift, available at the website of the Institute for Policy Studies. Detail on the UK campaign for a High Pay Commission can be found at compassonline.org.uk. For other references, email the author at editor–at–toomuchonline.org.